Êóðñîâàÿ ðàáîòà: Attaction of foreign inflows in East Asia
Êóðñîâàÿ ðàáîòà: Attaction of foreign inflows in East Asia
RUSSIAN STATE
PEDAGOGICAL UNIVERSITY BY HERZEN
Economic faculty
Department of applied
economy
Course work on theme:
ATTACTION OF FOREIGN
INFLOWS IN EAST ASIA
Student of the third
course
_________________
Superviser of studies,
Candidate of economic
science,
Senior lecturer
Linkov Alexei Yakovlevich
St. Petersburg
2000 y.
Plan
1. Integration, globalization
and economic openness- basical principles in attraction of capital inflows
2. Macroeconomic
considerations
3. Private investment:
a) Commercial banks
b) Foreign direct portfolio
investment
4. Problems of official investment
and managing foreign assets liabilities
5. Positive benefits from
capital inflows
International economic
organizations (IEOs), such as the World Bank, the World Trade Organization
(WTO), and the International Monetary Fund (IMF), have bun promoting economic
openness and integration, centered on free trade and capital flows. as not a
complement but a substitute for national development strategy.
Investment
efforts in South Korea and Taiwan were underwritten by active government
strategy, including subsidies, promotion, tax incentives, socialization of
risk, and establishment of public enterprises. Singapore’s economic growth was
also predicated on a high investment strategy implemented by the government,
even though Singapore relied relatively more on foreign investors than the
other East Asian countries did.
Regionalism is
likely to remain an important factor in global economic relations in the
foreseeable future, as countries continue to strive for greater access to
foreign markets and for solutions to economic problems and disputes that in
many cases might be resolved only through regional cooperation.
Managing large
and perhaps variable capital inflows- or, more aptly, managing the economy in
such a manner as to effectively and productively absorb these flows- is a major
challenge for East Asian countries. Each country has embarked in its own
financial markets, following initiatives in trade liberalization. Until
recently, the bulk of capital inflows in East Asia has been FDI and project- related
lending, both official and private. At the relativly lower levels of a decade
ago, these flows could be readily accomodated. The overall impact of foreign
investment on growth and exports has been very positive. As the capital flows
have increased, they have created macroeconomic pressures on exchange rates,
domestic absorption, investment policies, and the capacities of domestic
capital markets. The more recent expansion of portfolio investment implies much
more integration into global capital markets and a corresponding increase in
exposure to international market discipline- refferred to by some as market-
conditionality- that will circumscribe policy options and limit the range of
possible deviation from global norms on a number of variables.
The increased
complexity of these poses serious policy challenges to authorities, whose
primary objective is to promote real sector growth in economies in which the
industrial and financial sectors are still rapidly evolving.
Achieving
sustainable, rapid growth with open capital accounts and active capital markets
my will be more difficult than was true with the more closed financial
structures that used to be the norm in East Asia. Indeed, concern about losing
control of domestic policy contributed to some governments reluctance to
liberalize their financial sector and capital accounts in the past, and
contributes to their willingness to stop the process if they see it getting out
of hand. However, capital controls are becoming more porous, the pressures to
liberalize stronger, and the benefits from more open financial sectors more
compelling Government preferences and market forces are liberalization. East
Asian countries can continue their rapid growth only if they achieve the
efficiency gains that result from further liberalization. Furthermore, less
distorted markets provide fewer opportunities, for sent-seeking behavior and
resource misallocation caused by price and other market distortions.
As capital,
domestic and foreign, to seek the highest rate of return in only market.
Investment levels in countries that offer strong growth potential can be
augmented by flows of foreign saving. At the same time, sophisticated investors
have expanded opportunities to seek short-term gain from exploiting market
imperfections, implicit guarantees, and price fluctuations.
These latter
activities and the extent to which they influence other portfolio investments
are more worrisome because of their volatility and their potential impact on
long-term policy. They may or may not be responding to fundamentals.
Theoretically, speculation and arbitrage are believed to contribute to
efficient markets and to impose few net costs overall. Market forces
represented by these speculative flows have generally, but not always, created
pressures toward needed corrections, either of fundamental policy unbalances or
of unwarranted implicit guarantees or distortions.
However,
short-term traders can exert a great deal of influence on specific markets as
specific times, with can work against government policy objectives. It is
argued that short-term traders would do this only if policies were wrongheaded,
but in practice market forces make no judgments as to the inherent value of a
policy- only as to whether a profit can be made from expected market movements.
Market agents have been known to err and overshoot (although policymakers
probably anticipate or perceive more errors than are likely to occur).
Nevertheless, it is not generally wise policy to try to resist market pressures
on the theory that they may be wrong. They are not often wrong, and resistance
can be expensive, since today private international markets can mobilize vastly
larger sums than even industrial country governments. When market forces do err
or overshoot, they correct themselves usually quickly enough to avoid much
lasting harm. In fact, quick policy reaction when the market is applying
pressure in response to some perceives profit opportunity often sends a signal
that large gains are unlikely and mitigates the flow, whereas digging in
against market trends may set up an easy win for speculators at the
government’s expense. Moreover, where policy failures contribute to market
pressures, resistance to adjustment can be vary expensive. The burden is on
governments to manage their economies so that easy arbitrage opportunities are
not readily available and official policies or actions do not give rise to
implicit guarantees or other distortions that markets can exploit to the
detriment of public objectives. Consistent application of sound policy and
clear direction goes a ling way toward reducing the likelihood of overreaction
by markets. In addition, policymakers can blunt short-term flows that pose
dangers to the economy through a variety of instruments that reduce speculative
short-term gains.
Governments
should naturally exercise caution in opening financial markets to international
flows. Liberalization needs to be predicated on (a) developing an appropriate
regulatory framework and supervisory system, (b) ensuring that the resulting
incentives promote prudent behavior, and (c) adopting a macroeconomic policy
structure that is consistent with open financial flows. Policies need to
promote both domestic and international equilibrium, be flexible enough to
respond to disturbances from the capital markets, and include safety features
to activate in periods of crisis. Even with such precautions, the world is a
highly uncertain and unpredictable place. There can be no assurances against
unforeseen crises, even with the best of policies. This is part of the price of
open market economies. The point is not to stifle an the economy in order to
avoid crises but to ensure that the economy is sufficiently flexible and robust
to weather the crises and continue to develop and liberalize despite such
interruptions.
The basic the
theoretical framework for analyzing the impact of external capital flows
derives from the pioneering work done by Flemming (1962) and Mundell (1963) on
open- economy stabilization policies. Their relatively simple models have been
revised as the issues addressed have become more complex. Policy guidelines
have become more complicated and much more dependent on a host of other factors
that affect economic activity, including expectations, which can be hard to pin
down. The theory provides a useful backdrop and guide for appropriate policy
responses, but practical policymaking requires a thorough understanding of the
characteristics of the economy in question, the exact nature of the capital
flows, and the range of available policy options and tradeoffs. East Asian
policymakers have been adept at pursuing reform until difficulties arise, then
slowing or even backtracking a bit to reassess and make corrections before
moving ahead once more. This pragmatism has proved its worth, as these
countries have generally avoided major crises.
The basic
theoretical models were initially developed to study the relative effects of
monetary and fiscal policies in achieving domestic stabilization. Impacts on
the external equilibrium were viewed as results and perhaps as constrains.
Critical to the analysis if the exchange regime- fixed or floating- and the
openness of the capital account (or the degree of substitutability between
domestic and financial capital assets).
Under most
conditions, the models indicate, that given a fixed nominal exchange rate
regime, fiscal policy is relatively more powerful than monetary policy in
affecting domestic output. Expansionary fiscal policy increases demand for
domestic goods but also tends to raise interest rates as additional public
borrowing is required. Higher interest rates attract more foreign capital,
increasing reserves. The increase in domestic resources to that sector. The
current account balance deteriorates, partly absorbing the increased capital
flows. Real currency appreciation occurs as domestic prices rise, even though
the nominal rate if fixed.
Conversely,
monetary policy has a greater effect on the external account. Raising domestic
interest rates attracts foreign capital and builds reserves, the amount
depending on the substitutability of foreign and domestic assets. Attempts to
stimulate domestic demand by lowering interest rates are diluted, as capital
flows overseas to seek higher rates there, reducing any effect on domestic demand.
The more substitutable foreign and domestic assets are, the less the interest
rate change required for a given effect. Increased substitutability of assets
leads to other problems, however. Where governments try to constrain domestic
demand by raising interest rates, capital flows in, to benefit the higher
rates, and counteracts the restraint. If sterilization is attempted- if, for
example, governments sell bonds (tending to further increase domestic interest
rates) to absorb the increase in the money supply associated with the influx
overwhelm the authorities’ ability to continue to issue bonds to purchase
foreign exchange. In such circumstance, it is hand to prevent a real currency
appreciation.
For an economy
dependent on export growth, as most East Asian countries are, the dangers of
expansionary fiscal policy, combined with monetary constraint to keep inflation
under control, are evident. East Asian countries generally adopt more
conservative fiscal stances than Latin American countries.
Under a floating-rate
regime, the additional exchange rate flexibility dampens some of these effects,
but at the cost of loss of control over the nominal exchange rate. Fiscal
policy becomes relatively lass effective in influencing domestic output. The
increase in demand from expansion leads to an appreciation of the nominal (and,
consequently, the real) exchange rate, increased imports and lower exports, and
less demanded for money and bonds.
Interest rates
rise, but less than in the fixed-rate case, and the floating rate keeps the
external accounts in balance. The increase in capital inflows offsets the
higher current account deficit. Under most reasonable assumptions, output
rises, but less than under a fixed exchange rate for a given increase in
expenditures. By contrast, monetary policy can have a more compelling effect.
An expansionary action, such as open market purchase of domestic bonds,
increases output through the effects of money supply on demand. It also leads
to a depreciation, which shifts resources to the tradable sector and decreases
the current account deficit, offsetting the outflow of capital brought about by
the more perfect substitutability of assets, although the interest rate change
will be smaller.
These models can
also be used in reverse to examine the effects of a change in external
variables on the domestic economy. What are the implications when we look at
the effect on domestic policy of increases in foreign capital inflows? For a
regime with a fixed nominal exchange rate, an increase in foreign inflows tends
to reduce the domestic interest rate and increase domestic demand. This, in
turn, leads to an increase in domestic prices that will bring about a real
appreciation through higher domestic inflation. Reserves tend to accumulate,
although by less than the capital inflows, as the current account also
deteriorates. Monetary policy action to absorb the capital inflows through, for
example, open-market sales of bonds (sterilized intervention) could offset the
impact on demand. But such an action would tend to increase interest rates,
which could well attract more capital inflow. It is not likely to be effective
in the long term if there are practical limits on how many bonds can be issued,
and it could be costly (because of negative carry on the reserves accumulated).
The more substitutability there is between domestic and foreign assets, the
less variance is possible between domestic and foreign interest rates before
increase in the domestic interest rate become self-defeating. Fiscal contraction
would offset the increase in demand and perhaps allow a reduction in interest
rates, which would diminish the attraction of domestic assets to foreign
investors. A fiscal response would take longer to orchestrate than a monetary
response, however, become public budgets are hard to cut in the short run.
Under a
floating-rate regime, a foreign capital inflow leads directly to an
appreciation of the nominal and real exchange rates. The impact on output
depends on the relative strengths of the increase in demand resulting from the
capital inflow and the reduction in demand for domestic output because of the
appreciation, but an increase in output is likely. If the exchange rate is
allowed to adjust, the real appreciation attributable to the capital inflow has
less effect on the domestic economy. Prices may rise, and interest rates may
fall. However, for export-oriented economies a sustained appreciation may pose
serious long-term problems for the export sector. Many fear that appreciation
would cause significant loss of exports and eventually overall growth, as
markets are lost to lower-cost competitors. Depending on the relative strengths
of different effects, the expansion of domestic demand could be counteracted by
either tighter fiscal policy or monetary contraction, offsetting some of the
appreciation. The former still raises the same questions about the speed of
response; the latter may raise interest rates enough to attract more foreign
inflows, exacerbating the initial problem. Furthermore, exchange rate
appreciation induced by capital inflows will increase the yield to foreign
investors as measured in their own currencies, which may extend the capital
inflows, particularly short-term, yield-sensitive flows. The ability of
floating exchange rates to insulate an economy from external influences depends
on the authorities’ willingness to accept exchange rate movements determined,
in part, by foreign investment demand. A floating-rate regime also depends on
the flexibility of domestic prices and wages and on adequate factor mobility to
be effective. The prevailing fixed or managed exchange rate regimes in East
Asia and most other countries indicate a marked reluctance to accept the
implications of fully floating exchange rates.
Even at this
simple level, the models illustrate several important points. The degree of
openness of the capital account and the substitutability of foreign and
domestic assets have an important bearing not only on financial sector policies
but also on real sector policies. Financial flows can have tremendous effects
on the real economy – for example, on interest and exchange rates and, through
those variables, on output, employment, and trade . The more open an economy
and he more integrated into world capital markets, the harder it is for the
country to maintain interest rates that deviate significantly from world rates
or an exchange rate that is far out of line with what markets believe to be
proper. The market’s views on these rates are driven by many short-and
medium-term considerations and, particularly for interest rates by forces in
the major financial markets. Market pressures on a given country’s capital
markets reflect a great deal more than just the fundamentals of a particular
country. Countries cannot afford to have key policy variables that are
inconsistent with global trends. Thus the capital account’s openness exposes
the economy to pressures that may complicate achievement of the country’s
long-term real sector objectives, and stabilization issues must be more finely balanced
against growth objectives. Integration into capital markets has its price.
To be more
realistic in these models, one can admit leakage’s and other factor- such as
unemployed resources, market imperfections, and expectations- that may mintage
or enhance the basic impacts described above. Introducing greater
sophistication increases the complexity and number of variables that must be
considered in reaching any conclusion, but it does not make reaching a
conclusion any easier. In fact, the results can be less determinant. The amount
of unemployment in the economy affects the extent to which changes in aggregate
demand move output or prices. In developing economies with limited factor
mobility among sectors, the question of unemployed resources may have to be
considered on a sectoral as well as an aggregate level, or by skill level.
Depending on the particular model used, the inclusion of expectation function
private investors will apply to any government action or nonaction. In some
cases, where governments have announced a commitment to protect exchange rates
or fix interest rates, guesswork is reduced for the market, but possibly at the
cost of offering privat speculative investors a largely covered bet. In other
cases it is much harder to predict whether a policy course outlined by a
government will be seen as credible. In factor in a policy’s effectiveness. The
history of government commitment and the market’s estimation of the resources
the government has available to defend a position figure into this equation.
Although models provide useful general guidance and help frame the issues,
their implementation must be tempered by an analysis of the features of
practical considerations.
The basic
dilemma stems from the role of the exchange rate (nominal for-term transactions
and real for long-term decisions) in equilibrating both goods and capital
markets as they become more open. Heretofore, developing countries in East Asia
and elsewhere have been able to use the level and movement of the exchange rate
to effect the goods market almost exclusively. East Asian countries have often
used nominal deprecations to maintain stable or slightly falling real exchange
rates and so promote exports.
As capital
markets open capital flows can create pressures to appreciate the real or
nominal exchange rate against targets directed toward the goods market.
Attempts to maintain a rate satisfactory for the goods market without adjusting
other policy instruments can lead to disruptive capital flows. Either the
exchange rate target has to be modified, or other policy instruments must be
adjusted. Using the exchange rate as a “nominal anchor” to help combat
inflation adds to the burden and can be effective only where fiscal and
monetary policies are closely coordinated in support of that objective. In
countries with less developed financial sectors, the choice and range of
instruments are limited.
As the
theoretical models have become richer and more complex, so have the range and
complexity world. Most of the stabilization models deal with money and simple
bonds as assets and include little, if any, explicit analysis of risk- except
as the degree of substitutability of domestic and foreign assets may be taken
as a partial proxy for differing risk. The models do not look at the
differential impacts of different types of capital flow can be quite different.
Policymakers need to look at the characteristics of the instruments involves in
capital movements in both a short-term and a medium-term perspective to help
formulate policy.
Commercial bank
borrowing provides resources that are essentially untied. Where the capital
flow is directly linked to a specific project, its impact will be in the
capital goods markets. It will probably have a high import content, witch will
absorb a portion of the increase in demand from the capital inflow and ease
pressure to appreciate the exchange rate or raise domestic prices. However,
because these flows are flexible, they can readily be used to finance budget
shortfalls of the government or of enterprises, perhaps delaying necessary
fundamental adjustment, as often happened leading up to the debt crisis of the
1980s. In that case they increase aggregate demand and are more likely to lead
to inflationary pressure and exchange rate appreciation. Because of its fixed
term, the stock of this form of capital is not likely to be volatile. However,
flows can stop abruptly, leading to economic stresses, particulary where
borrowers have come to rely on foreign flows and have allowed domestic savings
to decline. Excessive dependence on commercial bank flows can be risky because
there are few built-in hedges to protect the borrower against exchange and
interest rate fluctuations. Furthermore, repayment schedules are fixed in
foreign exchange, and provision must be made to service this debt on schedule,
regardless of the state of the economy of then project financed.
Foreign direct
investment initially affects the market for real assets through purchases of
new capital goods and construction services for plant constructions and sales
of firms to foreign investors, or, in the case of privatization’s and sales of
firms to foreign investors, through purchases of existing plant and equipment.
Direct investors may even encourage incremental national saving and investment,
either from local partners or from bank borrowing. FDI in new plant increases
the aggregate demand for investment goods, and frequently of other goods as
well. Higher demand for imports eases the pressure of capital inflow on the
domestic, reduces reserve accumulation, and relieves pressure on the exchange
rate. Most FDI in East Asia has been of this productive type, and its impact
has been manageable. When FDI is in a protected industry, as has occurred in
some cases, the profits it earns may not come from real (as opposed to
accounting) value added. This form of FDI is least beneficial, as it exploits
local marker imperfections to the advantage of the foreign investor and may not
increase domestic value added or measured or wealth measured in world prices.
The eventual repatriation of capital and profits could reduce the host real
income and wealth.
FDI attracted by
privatization programs is not as likely to result in much new investment.
(Depending on the terms of sale, the new owner may be required to undertake a
certain amount of new investment or renovate existing equipment). When an
existing domestic asset is sold, there is no direct increase in the capital
stock, although the productivity of the existing capital should increase. FDI
received is available for whatever purpose the seller chooses, including
reducing an external gap, lowering taxes, or sustaining other current
expenditures. The effect depends other current expenditures. The effect depends
on what the seller (the government, in the case of privatization, or a private,
in the case of a private asset sale to foreign interests) does with the
proceeds: reduce other debt (which might ease pressure in the banking system),
invest in another project (which would increase investment, as discussed
above), or spend on other goods, primary consumption (which would increase
aggregate demand and perhaps imports, with no increase in output capacity). To
the extent that capital inflows support increased imports without a
corresponding increase in investment, domestic saving are reduced.
FDI lows are as
sustainable as the underlying attraction- stable policies and profitable
opportunities. To the extent that an economy’s growth depends on a sustained
inflow of FDI- for the level of investment, for technology and skill transfer,
or for supporting an export strategy- the importance of maintaining those
conditions is evident. Although FDI is not readily reversible, sharp drops on
new flows can have repercussions if countries depend on it for future export growth.
Similarly, to the extent that countries have increased resources derived from
the foreign investment, a reduction in those flows will require perhaps
difficult adjustments on the consumption front.
No contractual
repayments are associates with FDI. Investors expect a return on their
investment- generally a higher rate of return that on loans and bonds because
of the higher risks and opportunity costs involved. Malaysia, which has been
the beneficiary of substantial FDI, has grown rapidly: an estimated one- third
of its current account receipts is now claimed by service payments on FDI. When
FDI flows are sustained over a long period, foreigners inevitably came to own a
substantial portion of the country’s capital stock in the sectors that attracted
FDI. This prospect is not viewed with as much concern as it once was FDI is not
likely to be volatile: once invested, the real asset is not going to more,
although changes in ownership are possible. Eventually, a foreign investor may
want to sell to a local partner or divest onto a local stock market, and the
host country needs to be prepared for a repatriation of capital. In times of
stress, however, investor may well find ways to get their capital out quickly.
Many investors set as a target the recouping of their outlays (which are
usually less than total project cost) within two or three years, through
repatriated) profits.
|
|
 |
Composition
of Net Private Capital Flows (in billions of 1985 U.S. dollars)
FPI potentially
has a much wider range of effects, depending on the type of instrument and how
it is used. It can occur through securities placed in foreign or domestic
markets, including short-term funds and demand deposits. (The relation of these
two instruments to physical investment may be limited; they may be much more a
function of financial variables). Although many of its impacts can be similar
to those of bank loans and FDI, portfolio investment can also have a much
greater effect on domestic capital markets and interest rates. Whereas direct
investment regimes, portfolio flows raise issues of financial and capital
market regimes and their management. Portfolio investment touches more on
issues of disclosure, accounting, and auditing that does direct investment.
When portfolio
investment takes the form of an external placement (bond or equity) and the
funds are used to finance new investment, the effects are in the real sector,
as discussed for FDI. If the funds are used for other purposes, the result
depends on those purposes. Paying down debt might ease pressure in the banking
sector or build reserves. If the inflow is subsequently invested in domestic
capital markets or deposited in banks, the money supply and domestic credit
expand. Demand for assets, including real estate, would probably increase, with
effects similar to those of foreign investment in local markets (discussed
below). If the funds are used for consumption, pressure on domestic output
could increase, leading to a rise in prices. These uses are likely to put more
upward pressure on the exchange rate and downward pressure on interest rates, as
the prices of nontradables and domestic assets are bid up. This is true whether
the government or the private sector carries out the initial borrowing or stock
issue. Offshore placement do not give rise to volatility concerns in the
issuing country’s market. Subsequent trading in the asset occurs in the foreign
market and does not result in further capital movements, other than normal
repayments, into or out of the borrowing country. Sustained access to foreign
markets if another matter; if depends on the market’s continued positive
assessment of the borrower, the liquidity of the borrower’s paper, and the
borrower’s compliance with market rules. If circumstances lead to price
volatility in foreign markets, new placements will be inhibited.
In some East Asian
countries (Indonesia, Korea, and Thailand) domestic banks have been major
issuers of bonds into external markets. Since 1990, 40 percent of placements
have been by financial institutions, with banks accounting for 27 percent.
Large banks obviously have better credit rating than many of their clients and
are thus able to raise funds less expensively. This is a legitimate
intermediation function and has opened financing opportunities to many domestic
firms that would otherwise have had less access to funds. For the ultimate
borrower, lower interest rates, not foreign exchange rates, are typically the
critical factor. For the intermediating banks, the spreads and volumes are
attractive, and the operations help establish the bank’s international
presence. These actions, however, pose two risks. First, there may be a
relative decrease in the effectiveness of monetary police, since in the
effectiveness of monetary policy, since the financial system can miligate or
offset government attempts to expand or contract credit by modulating its
foreign borrowing for domestic clients. When foreign interest rates are lower
than domestic rates, borrowers will be tempted to seek more funds abroad, which
may undermine domestic policies of monetary restraint. Second, banks (especially
public or quasi-public banks) may be borrowing abroad with the implicit or
explicit expectation of a government quartette. They may not take full account
of the exchange risk and may face interest risks as well, since they are
intermediating across currencies and between short-term liabilities and
long-term assets. These risks are likely to be passed on to the government,
should they adversely affect the banks. The recently reported instance of
BAPINDO, a troubled Indonesian bank that borrowed internatinally, seems to have
involved an implicit guarantee, as that bank would not have been able to borrow
on its own account. More generally, central banks may be forces to intervene to
protect the banking sector with official reserves if there are major disruptions
of commercial banks’ capacity to refinance abroad. For some large borrowers,
domestic markets may not yet be deep enough to absorb the size and other
requirements of their financing needs, so that these enterprises must turn to
international markets.
FPI in domestic
markets is a different matter. The bulk of this inflow has been in equities, as
investors have been seeking high yields, mostly through appreciation. These
flows purchase existing portfolio assets and sometimes new issues. To the extent
that the new issues fund new investment, the effects would be quite similar
would be owned by the domestic issuer rather than the foreign investor. New
issues may also be used to recapitalize existing operations. Here the effect
would be through the banking system and the rest of the domestic financial
market, where debt would be retired by the new equity-generated flows. Although
this could ease pressure on the banking system, it would tend to lower interest
rates and increase domestic liquidity. That, in turn, would increase aggregate
demand and create more pressure on the exchange rate than if the funds had been
invested in new equipment with a high import content.
The bulk of
equity investment has been into existing stocks in East Asian markets, driving
up the prices of equity. the cost of capital drops for those floating new
issues, but there are for also strong wealth effects on existing asset holders-
as their wealth increases, consumption is likely to go up as well. This will
tend to raise domestic prices and appreciate the currency in real terms,
Whether these foreign equity, investments increase physical investment depends
on the behavior of the other asset holders- those who sold to foreign investors
and those whose assets appreciated. If they invest in new projects, physical
investment will also increase, otherwise, it will not. It is more likely that
domestic savings will fall when there are large portfolio investment flows than
when the flows take the form of FDI. In Latin America, which has experienced
more portfolio inflows decline, rather than physical investment to increase. In
the past East Asia has avoided this result, partly because its overall policy
regime has favored investment, partly because of the greater degree of
sterilization it has been able to achieve, and partly because the share of
portfolio investment has been smaller. Portfolio flows are a very recent
phenomenon, and it is still to soon to measure many of their effects in East
Asia.
It is
particularly worrisome when large private capital flows move into commercial
real estate. Experience in many countries, both industrial and developing,
indicates the ease with which speculative bubbles can develop in real estate
during an investment boom. Asset inflation in this sector can generate very
high rates of return- much higher than are available from investment in
manufacturing- over a few years. But such rates are not sustainable. When the
bottom falls out, as it inevitably does, there are frequently severe
repercussions on the banking sector, since domestic banks are usually major
financiers of the real estate, and governments often end up bailing out the
financial sector. Indonesia faced this problem in 1993; Thailand saw carliev
bouts of these bubbles; and they are not unknown in other countries, including
the United States and Japan.
The
sustainability of flows into stock markets is a complex matter. To the extent
that the flows depend on continued high gains, mostly appreciation, one could
wonder whether the high of return of 1992-93 will resume after the 1994
correction. Even in the best of circumstances, one would expect some flow
reversals, in addition to normal volatility. Unfortunately, the best of
circumstances rarely occurs, and the Mexican episode of December 1994 has
precipitated outflows in many emerging markets as fund managers have bailed out
everywhere. It is hard not to view this as herd behavior with a tinge of panic,
but it caused a 3 percent devaluation in Thailand and more than doubled
short-term interest rates there. Other East Asian markets have also suffered
outflows as international investors have generally reduced their exposure in
emerging markets. However, giver the long-term growth potential of the East
Asian economies and the indications of a longer-term stock adjustment process,
there is reason to except that such reactions will be temporary set backs in a
persistent trend toward a lager share of sound emerging market stocks in global
portfolios. The spectacular yields witnessed recently may not be sustainable,
but the East Asian countries should offer high rates of return over the long
term and should continue to attract investment.
A number of
countries in East Asia and elsewhere have begun attracting foreign portfolio
investors into their own fixed-income markets ,purchasing, instruments in local
currency. In this case the foreign bondholder takes the exchange risk, for
which he expects added compensation. It is encouraging that these economies are
becoming attractive enough, and their exchange management is considered stable
enough, to attract investment in local currency securities. For obvious
reasons, interest tends to be in bank deposits, in shorter maturities, and in
guaranteed instruments of government or their agencies.
To the extent
that short-term capital flows exceed working balances, trade financing, or
bridge activities to long-term investment, they are most likely the result of
relatively high interest rates not offset by an expected devolution. For the
most part, these flows are seeking high short-term rates of return and reflect
cash management or speculative decisions rather than long-term investment
decisions rather than long-term investment decisions. But like long-term flows,
they tend to lower domestic interest rates and appreciate the exchange rate.
They are likely to expand bank reserves and lead to more credit expansion,
although on a potentially more volatile base. To the extend that a government
is trying to restrain domestic demand with high interest rates, the inflow
would undermine its policy. These flows may not directly influence long-term
savings and investment, but they may do so.
The World Bank
and investment bankers regularly provide advice to developing countries on
asset and liability management. But that advice often is non optimal or simply
wrong. Although many tactical tools for active risk management in developing
countries have been developed in the past decade, a framework for developing a
strategy that incorporates country-specific factors has lagged far behind.
For example, in
case when the Federal Reserve Bank (the “Fed”) last September arranged a $3.6
billion bailout of Long Term Capital Management (LTCM)- a Connecticut- based
hedge fund- critics of the US financial establishment cries foul. The bailout
contrasted strikingly with IMF treatment of indebted firms in Asia. When
indebted businesses in Asia were unable to replay foreign loads, US and IMF
officials insisted that they be forced to close and their assets sold off to
creditors. Bailing out ailing businesses with endless lines of bank credit was,
US officials claimed, the essence of “crony capitalism” and the cause of all
Asia’s problems “Reducing expectations of bailouts, ” declared the IMF, must be
step number one in restructuring Asia’s financial markets.
To Japanese
officials, the LTCM bailout was a clear case of the US “ignoring its own
principles”. Representative Bruce Vento (Democrat, Minnesota), in a
Congressional investigation of the LTCM bailout, said that “there seem to be
two rules, a double standard.” But this view is incorrect. Where bailouts are
concerned, there is only one standard. Whether in Korea, Thailand, Connecticut
or Brazil, US- and IMF- organized bailouts conform, to the same quiding
principle: whatever happens, whoever is at fault, the wealth of Western credits
must be protected and enhanced.
Until 1997,
Western creditors were bullish on Asia and “emerging markets” generally. They
poured billions into stocks, banks and businesses in Thailand, Indonesia,
Korea, expecting mega-returns and a piece of the action as the former “Third
World” embraced freemarket capitalism. Beginning in 1997, though, Western
investors began to worry that they might have over-lent. They pulled out of
Thailand first, selling baht for dollars; as the baht’s value collapsed, worry
turned to panic. Soon, international financial operators were selling won,
ringgit, rupiah and rubles in an effort to cut potential losses and get their
funds safety back to Europe and the US. In the ensuing capital flight, Asian stock
prices plunged and the value of Asian currencies collapsed. Local businesses
that had taken out dollar payments to Western creditors.
For a time,
local governments tries to stave off default by lending their reserves of
foreign currency to indebted firms. South Korea used up some $30 billion in
this way. But this money soon ran out. Western banks refused to make new loans
or roll over old debts. Asian businesses defaulted, cutting output and laying
off workers. As the economies worsened, panic intensified. Asian currencies
lost 35 to 85 per cent of their foreign- exchange value, driving up prices on
imported goods and pushing down the standard of living. Businesses large and
small were driven to bankruptcy by the sudden drying up of credit; within a year,
millions of workers had lost jobs while prices of basic foodstuffs soared.
As the crisis
unfolded, IMF officials flew to Asia to arrange a bailout, agreeing ultimately
to loan $120 billion to Thailand, Indonesia and South Korea. When announcing
these loans, the press used terms like “emergency assistance” and
“international rescue package,” leading the casual reader to presume that the
money will be spent on food for the hungry, or aid to the jobless. In float,
the money is used to “help” countries pay bank their debts to international
banks and brokerage houses. Which international banks and brokerage house? The
same ones who made speculative loans in the first place, then panicked and
brought about the collapse of the Asian economies. The IMF rescue packages are
intended only to rescue the Western creditors.
The Western
financial industry, moreover, has been lobbying heavily for even more secure
protection from future losses. One plan, put forward last year by the US and US
Treasuries, envisions a $90 billion fund of public money, supposedly to avert
currency crises. The idea is that G7 governments will, henceforth, underwrite
the finance industry’s speculative ventures into emerging, markets before,
rather than after, they turn sour. In this way, when bankers and fund mangers
grow bored with a particular market, withdraw their funds and send the currency
into a tailspin, they can collect on their losses immediately, without the
tedious and time- consuming delays generated by IMF negotiations.
The industry has
also been working overtime to squelch defensive government action against their
speculative attacks. At a recent conference in New York City, economist Jagdish
Bhagwati noted that the IMF and the US Government, despite repeated crises and
heavy criticism have intensities pressures on countries to lift exchange
controls. The IMF recently proposed changing its Articles of Agreement so as to
require countries to permit even more freedom for financial speculations.
Echoing this sentiment, US Treasury official Lawrence Summers decried efforts
by Malaysia, Hong Kong and other to curb foreign lending, calling capital
controls “a catastrophe” and urging countries to “open up to foreign financial
service” providers, and all the competition, capital and expertise they bring
with them.
Critics of IMF
and US policy have, of course, noted that the combination of free flowing
capital and bailout funds are a boon to banks other creditors. Such IMF critics
as financier George Soros and Harvard’s Jeffrey Sachs complain that the game of
international speculation and bailout played by the Western financial
establishment- in which hot money rushes into a country, then pulls out,
leaving behind a wrecked economy to be cleaned up by local governments and G7
taxpayers- is a menace to world economic stability. For the Western financial
establishment, however, the bailouts are not the real prize. Nor are the
devastated economies of Asia an unfortunate side-effect of a financial scamp.
They are the while point of the game. Asia’s bankrupt businesses, insolvent
banks and jobless millions are the spoils of what economist Michel Chossudovsky
aptly calls “financial warfare”. The gains to be won from these financial
hit-and-runs are immense. There are, first of all, the foreign- exchange
reserves of the target countries. Countries accumulate currency reserves by
running trade surpluses, often after year upon year of selling more abroad than
they purchase. These surpluses are accumulated at great cost to the working
populations, who labor hard to produce goods, destined to be consumed by
foreigners. In 1997-1998, Asian countries spent nearly $100 billion in
accumulated reserves trying- vainly as it turned out- to prevent devaluation.
Brazil, the latest country to fall, spent $36 billion defending the real
against speculators. Thus, in little over a year, did the Western financial
elite confiscate $136 billion of hard-won wealth from the emerging markets.
Next, there are
the bargains to be had once the target country’s currency has collapsed and its
firms are strapped for cash. Year of effort, for example, by the Korean elite
to keep businesses firmly under control of state-supported conglomerates called
chaebols were undone in a matter of months. By early 1998, as the IMF
negotiated the terms of surrender, Citigroup, Goldman Sachs and other firms
were snatching up ownership of Asian banks and industries. With currencies down
15-60 per cent and stock prices down 40-60 per cent, Asia is today a bargain-
hunter’s paradise. Nor are assets the only bargains to be had. As a direct
result of the destruction wrought by global financial interests, the prices of
basic commodities have plummeted over the past year. Oil. Copper, steel,
lumber, paper pulp, pork, coffee, rice can now be bought up by Western firms
dirt cheap, an important key to the continued profitability of US industry.
Then there is
the higher tribune that countries, once in debt peonage to Western creditors,
must pay on both old and new loans. South Korea, for example, under the terms
of the IMF bailout, will pay interest on foreign loans that is 25-30 per cent
higher that rates on comparable international loans- this despite the fact that
the loans have been guaranteed by the Korean Government. Since the crisis
began, international lenders have doubled or tripled the interest rates they
charge on emerging- market debt. What is such usurious interest cripples the
economy and drives the country into default? Well ,then they will become wards
of the IMF, lender of last resort.
Next, there are
the people themselves, engulfed in debt, impoverished and committed by their
governments to can endless course of domestic austerity and debt crisis of the
1980s, the Asian crisis has resulted in millions of newly unemployed, whose
desperation will pull wages down world-wide. Like the debt crisis of the 1980s,
the Asian crisis will turn entire countries into export platforms, where human
labor is transformed into the foreign exchange needed to repay Asia’s $600
billion debt. In just this past year, Thai rice exports rose by 75 per cent,
while Korea has managed to boost its exports and accumulate $41 billion in
reserves for debt service. These figures, notes the World Bank, indicate that
people in Asia “are working harder and eating less”.
Finally there
are the governments themselves, the ultimate prizes to be won. It is no
accident that conditions imposed by the IMF, with their emphasis on altering
state employment, welfare and pension systems, their insistence on reforming
the legal and political systems of the target countries, entail a major loss of
national sovereignty. Through IMF negotiations, national governments are
transformed into local enforcement agents of transnational corporations and
banks. IMF officials are quick to point out that the usurped governments often
were not paragons of democracy and virtue. This of course is true. But the
motives of the IMF are themselves profoundly undemocratic, intended to seize
sovereignty and fix the rules of the game and to protect and expand, at all
cost the wealth of the international financial elite.
Deposit Banks’ Foreign
Assets |
All countries |
1990 |
1991 |
1992 |
1993 |
1994 |
1995(I) |
6,793.4 |
6,753.5 |
6,780.4 |
7,239.0 |
7,907.9 |
8,568.9 |
Developing countries |
1,672.47 |
1,710.26 |
1,721.40 |
1,821.60 |
2,030.93 |
2,098.60 |
Asia |
868.69 |
884.06 |
891.33 |
928.57 |
1,068.13 |
1,135.63 |
Deposit Banks’ Foreign
Liabilities |
All countries |
1990 |
1991 |
1992 |
1993 |
1994 |
1995(I) |
7,137.0 |
6,994.7 |
6,945.9 |
7,099.6 |
8,047.7 |
8,689.8 |
Developing countries |
1,681.28 |
1,703.69 |
1,735.69 |
1,859.19 |
2,105.00 |
2,200.18 |
Asia |
838.28 |
861.37 |
869.10 |
929.69 |
1,093.74 |
1,181.70 |
How a market
develops, including the orderly introduction of new instruments, is an
important element of managing capital flows. In a broader since, the kinds of
instruments available and favored (by the tax structure or by other
regulations) in a market and the extent of foreign ownership allowed may also
have an effect on the allocation of investment in the real sector. For example,
in markets in which bonds are readily available or pension funds are impotent
buyers, more capital is likely to be available for long- gestating projects.
Two conclusions
emerge from this analysis. First, capital flows are inherently neither good nor
bad. They have a great potential to be either, depending on how productively
they are used or on whether they are allowed to distort economic incentives and
decisions. The contrast between growth in East Asia and stagnation in Latin
America is instructive in this regard (There are significant exceptions to this
generalization in both regions- the Philippines and other countries come to
mind). Second, realizing positive benefits from capital inflows depends on
sound macroeconomic and sectoral policies in the recipient country. Capital
flows are a complement to good policy, not a substitute for it.
The List of Literature.
1. Managing Capital Flows in East Asia. A world Bank
Publication. Wash 1996y.
2. Private Market Financing for Developing Countries.
IMF wash 1995 y.
3. The World Economy Global trade policy Edited by
Sven Arndt and Chris Milner. Oxford , 1996 y.
4. International Studies Review Edited by ISA and
Thomas S. Watcon Oxford Milner Sping 2000 y.
6. The Would Bank Research
Program. The Would Bank Research.
7. Alan Greespon. Financial
markets //New Internation-list. may 1999 y. c15-16